JORGE RODRIGUES SIMAO

ADVOCACI NASCUNT, UR JUDICES SIUNT

(1) European Union Crisis

The European Debt Crisis Visualized

EUcrisis1

EUROPE HAS LONG PRIDED ITSELF on being a model for the rest of the world of how to reconcile old enemies after centuries of war, blend the power of capitalism with social justice and balance work with leisure. Little matter that Europeans did not generate as much wealth as overworked Americans; Europeans took more time off to enjoy life. And little matter that Europe could not project the same military force as the United States; Europe saw itself as a “normative power”, able to influence the world through its ability to set rules and standards. Some Europhiles even imagined that Europe would “run the 21st century”, as the title of one optimistic book put it.

The collapse of subprime mortgages in the United States, and the credit crunch that followed, only confirmed such convictions. The single currency, the European Union’s most ambitious project, was seen as a shield against financial turbulence caused by runaway American “ultra-liberalism”, as the French liked to describe the faith in free markets. But when the financial storm blew in from across the Atlantic, the euro turned out to be a flimsy umbrella that flopped over in the wind and dragged away many of the weaker economies. It led to the worst economic and political crisis in Europe since the Second World War.

Starting in May 2010, first Greece, then Ireland and Portugal were rescued and had to undergo painful internal devaluation, that is, by reducing wages and prices relative to others. The process proved so messy and bitter that, even with hundreds of billions of euros committed to bail-outs, the currency several times came close to breaking up, potentially taking down the single market and perhaps the whole EU with it. The EU’s hope of becoming a global power dissolved as Europe became the world’s basket case. More than once, the United States forcibly pressed its transatlantic allies and economic partners to do more to fix their flawed currency union.

At the time of writing, in March 2014, the euro zone has survived the financial crisis – an achievement in itself, but won at too high a price. The euro zone bottomed out of its double-dip recession in 2013. But despite signs of “Europhoria” in markets the danger is far from over. Among Europhiles and Eurosceptics alike, there is a growing belief that the euro has undermined, and may yet destroy, the European Union. Instead of promoting economic integration, euro-zone economies have diverged. Rather than sealing post-war reconciliation, the euro is creating resentment between north and south. Far from settling the age-old German question, Germany has emerged as all-powerful. The decline of France has accelerated, and the ungovernability of Italy has been reaffirmed. Tensions between euro “ins” and “outs” have increased, particularly in the case of the UK, which now hovers ever closer to the exit.

The chronic democratic problem has become acute: the EU is intruding ever more deeply into national policymaking, particularly in the euro zone, without becoming any more accountable to citizens. Perversely, the clearest sign of a common political identity, the European “demos” that federalists hoped would emerge is to be found in anti-European movements. For now the riots and clouds of tear gas in Greece and the mass protests by Spain’s indignados may have faded away. But almost everywhere, apart from Germany, which has barely felt the crisis, indignant voters have thrown out incumbent governments and abandoned centrist parties in large numbers. Anti-EU and anti-euro parties are on the rise, of both left- and right-wing varieties, in both core and periphery countries, and in both euro ins and euro outs. The scariest are in Greece, which has both radical leftists and neo-Nazi extremists, and has witnessed murderous violence among their followers. But the most consequential may yet be the scrubbed-up, be suited populists in countries such as France, the Netherlands and the UK, which were hardly the worst hit by the debt crisis. They have already changed the terms of the European debate in these countries. Once the champion of EU enlargement, the UK is increasingly turning against the cherished right of free movement of workers, and against the EU itself.

As the countries of the euro-zone periphery seek to regain competitiveness, their most striking export has been young emigrants in search of jobs abroad. These are no longer the manual workers of yesteryear who filled the factories of Germany, the mines of Belgium and the building sites of the UK.

Now it is the young graduates who are on the move. In Portugal, the post-colonial flow has reversed, as hopefuls head out to Brazil, Angola and Mozambique in search of a better life. In Ireland, some churches have set up webcams so that émigré parishioners can watch services back home. Many have moved to other parts of Europe, notably Germany.

1. “If the euro fails, Europe fails”

IN THE SPRING AND SUMMER OF 2012 there was a fad in offering advice on how to break up the euro.

More than two years after the start of the Greek debt crisis, the experiment of the single European currency seemed to be close to failure. Successive bail-outs, crushing austerity and innumerable emergency summits that produced at best a half-hearted response were stoking resentment among creditor and debtor countries alike. And since national leaders seemed either unwilling or unable to weld together a closer union, the pressure of the euro crisis was remorselessly pushing the cracks apart. Better, thought some, to attempt an orderly dissolution than to be confronted with a chaotic break-up.

In May the former chief economist at Deutsche Bank, Thomas Mayer, proposed the introduction of a parallel currency for Greece, a “Geuro”, to help the country devalue.1 In July Policy Exchange, a British think-tank, awarded the £250,000 Wolfson Prize for the best plan to break up the euro to Roger Bootle of Capital Economics,2 a private research firm in London. The following month The Economist published a fictitious memorandum to Angela Merkel, the German chancellor, setting out two options for a break-up: the exit of Greece alone, and the departure of a larger group of five countries that added Cyprus, Spain, Portugal and Ireland as well. A footnote reported that the ever-cautious Merkel had turned down both possibilities, deeming the risks to be too great, and ordered the paper shredded.“No one need ever know that the German government had been willing to think the unthinkable. Unless, of course, the memo leaked.”3

The imaginary memo was closer to the truth than readers might have thought. That summer Merkel did indeed ponder, and reject, the idea of throwing the Greeks out of the euro. German, European and IMF officials had by then drawn up detailed plans to manage a break-up of the euro – not to dissolve the currency completely but rather to try to preserve as much of it as possible if Greece (or another country) were to leave. The plans never leaked, which was just as well. The mere existence of a contingency plan for “Grexit” might have provoked a self-fulfilling panic in markets. Few had confidence that any plan to oversee an orderly break-up would work. Officials thought the unthinkable on at least three occasions.

The first was in November 2011, when Greece announced a referendum on its second bail-out programme. Germany and France, outraged by Greece’s insubordination, demanded that the referendum question had to be whether Greece wanted to stay in the euro or not. For the first time, European leaders were openly entertaining the notion of Grexit. In the event the vote was abandoned after the fall, within days, of the prime minister, George Papandreou. The second moment of peril came between the two Greek elections in May and June of 2012, when the rise of radical parties of the left and the right increased the risk of the Greeks voting themselves out of the euro before cooler heads prevailed in the second ballot. (Even after the conservative leader, Antonis Samaras, had put together a government that belatedly committed itself to the EU adjustment programme, Merkel debated well into August over whether to expel Greece.)

The third danger point was the tough negotiation over the bail-out for Cyprus in March 2013. The newly elected president, Nicos Anastasiades, threatened to leave the currency if a bail-out meant destroying the island’s two largest banks and wiping out their big expatriate (mostly Russian) depositors. After two rounds of ugly negotiations Anastasiades succumbed to his rescuers. The euro zone would have been ill-prepared to cope with Grexit in late 2011. Jean-Claude Trichet, who presided over the ECB until the end of October 2011, would not countenance detailed doomsday planning. And without the central bank’s power to create money, a break-up might have been uncontrollable. Trichet’s successor, Mario Draghi, did set up a crisis-management team in January 2012. Within a year the ECB and the IMF had developed an hour-by-hour, day-by-day plan to try to manage the departure of a euro-zone member. By the time of the negotiations with Cyprus, admittedly a smaller country than Greece or the other rescued economies, the prospect of Cyprexit did not cause anywhere near the same degree of fear among officials, or markets.

Others also worked up contingency plans, not least in the European Commission and the European Council, though here co-ordination was weaker for fear of disclosure. “Everything in Brussels leaks,” says one of those involved. Officials recount how on one occasion Herman Van Rompuy, president of the European Council, raised the prospect of Grexit with José Manuel Barroso, president of the Commission. “I don’t want to know the details. But I hope you are taking care of it,” Van Rompuy said. Even so, his own small team of economists also quietly worked up position papers. It all made for a strange dance in the darkness. Within the Commission, staff at the economics directorate had been expressly ordered not to do any work on the response to a possible break-up, even though a discreet group of senior commissioners and officials did just that: plan for a split in the currency zone. They had two main purposes: first, to set out what would have to be done; and second, to make the case for why it should not be done. For others it was a matter of managing as well as possible. For all concerned a big dilemma was how much to tell the Greek authorities about the preparations for their country’s possible return to the drachma. The answer was: hardly anything at all.

Like the gold standard, only worse

Fixed exchange-rate systems have fallen apart throughout history, from the gold standard to various dollar pegs. But giving up a fixed peg is very different from scrapping an entire currency. This has happened too, but usually only when political unions have broken apart: for instance, the break-up of the Austro-Hungarian empire, the collapse of the Soviet Union or the velvet divorce between the Czech Republic and Slovakia. And none of these precedents quite captures the special circumstances of the euro. It is a single currency without a single government. It is made up of rich countries, many of which have built up large debts and large external imbalances, so the sums at stake are proportionately large. A map of the world sized according to each country’s government spending shows Europe as a huge, puffed-up ball of public money.4 Moreover, the euro zone is a subset of the European Union and its single market, within which goods, services, capital and people move more or less freely. As a result, the spillover effects on other European countries would be that much greater. It had taken years for countries to prepare for the introduction of the euro. If any left, they might have to adapt to the redenomination of a member’s currency overnight, or at best over a weekend.

Nobody could be sure about the consequences should the supposedly irrevocable currency become revocable. There were two prevailing beliefs. One was the amputation theory: severing a gangrenous limb such as Greece would save the rest of the body. The other was the domino theory: the fall of one country would lead to the collapse of one economy after another. Grexit might thus be followed by Portexit, Spexit, Italexit and even Frexit.

Given such uncertainties, the objective for officials preparing contingency plans was clear: regardless of which country left the euro, the rest must be held together almost at any cost. Those involved speak only in guarded terms about precisely what they would have done. Would the departure of, say, Greece have required Cyprus to leave as well, given their close interconnection? The ECB would have flooded the financial system with liquidity to try to ensure that credit markets did not dry up, as they had done after the collapse of Lehman Brothers, and to forestall runs on both banks and sovereigns. Large quantities of banknotes would have been made available in the south to reassure anxious depositors especially if, as during the Cyprus crisis, banks were shut down and capital controls imposed. The ECB would probably have engaged in unprecedented bond-buying to hold down the borrowing costs of vulnerable countries. Loans to countries already under bail-out programmes would have been increased, and some kind of precautionary loan extended to Spain and Italy.

The IMF would have helped Greece manage the reintroduction of the drachma. This would probably have required a transition period (perhaps as short as one month) involving a parallel currency, or IOUs akin to the “patacones” that circulated in Argentina after it left its dollar peg in

2000, though EU lawyers thought these would be illegal. The ECB would have dealt with the technicalities of adapting European electronic payment systems to the departure of a member. The Commission would introduce guidelines for capital controls. Greece might have needed additional aid to manage the upheaval, not least to buy essential goods. In what remained of the euro zone there would have been difficult decisions to take over the allocation of losses arising within the Eurosystem of central banks. National governments would have to decide who should be compensated for losses in case of default and the inevitable bankruptcies caused by the abrupt mismatch between assets and liabilities as the values of currencies shifted. They might also have increased deposit guarantees, although in some cases that might have done more harm than good if the additional liability endangered public finances in weaker countries – as it had done in Ireland in 2008.

Perhaps, thought some, there should be a Europe-wide deposit guarantee. Indeed, many thought there would have to be a dramatic political move towards greater integration. Nobody quite knew what form this might take, but it would have had to signal an unshakeable commitment to stay together. Without the infuriating Greeks, greater integration might even appear more feasible. Indeed, it was such a prospect that convinced some senior EU officials that it would be a good idea to let the Greeks go after all: not because contagion could be contained, as the Bundesbank would sometimes claim, but precisely because it could not. Grexit would be so awful that it would force governments to make a leap into federalism.

Safe, for now

All these considerations, and more, were on Merkel’s mind in the summer of 2012 when she decided instead to keep the Greeks in. Beyond the financial price, Germany could not risk the political blame for breaking up the currency and, potentially, the European project itself. As she had repeatedly declared since the first bail-out of Greece in 2010, “if the euro fails, Europe fails”.

Two other events changed the dynamics of the crisis. First, at a summit in June, Merkel and other leaders agreed to centralise financial supervision around the ECB and then have the option of recapitalising troubled banks directly from the euro zone’s rescue funds. The move held out the promise, for the first time, of a banking union in which the risks of the financial sector would be shared. The aim was to break the doom-loop between weak banks and weak governments that threatened to destroy both, especially in Spain. The second, even more important, development that summer was Draghi’s declared readiness to intervene in bond markets without pre-set limits, on condition that troubled countries sought a euro-zone bail-out and adjustment programme. He thus sharply raised the cost of betting against the euro – to the point that, at the time of writing in March 2014, Draghi’s great bluff has yet to be called.

The euro has been saved, at least for a while. But even as economic output begins slowly to recover, the euro zone remains vulnerable and the wider European project remains under acute strain. As The Economist’s imaginary memo to Merkel noted, the contingency plans for the demise of the euro were never shredded; they were merely filed away. As The Economist’s imaginary memo to Merkel noted (see cover story headlined “Tempted, Angela?” in the issue of August 11th–17th 2012, the contingency plans for the demise of the euro were never shredded; they were merely filed away.

Notes:

1. Meyer, T., Der Geuro: Eine Parallelwährung für Griechenland? (in German), Deutsche Bank,

May 2012, available at: www.dbresearch.de/PROD/DBR_INTERNET_DEPROD/PROD0000000000288868.pdf.

 Some of Meyer’s arguments are reported in BusinessInsider, available at: http://www.businessinsider.com/introducing-the-geuro-a-new-parallel-currency-to-solve-all-of-greeces-problems-2012-5

Meyer himself sets out some of his views in this piece for the Wall Street Journal, available at:

http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB10001424127887324556304578116830518460210

 2. Roger Bootle et al., Leaving the Euro: A Practical Guide, Capital Economics, revised submission to the 2012 Wolfson Prize. This and other submissions are available at: http://www.policyexchange.org.uk/images/WolfsonPrize/wolfson%20economics%20prize%20winning%20entry.pdf

3. See “Tempted, Angela?” at www.economist.com/node/21560269

4. See page 22 of Gill, I.S. and Raiser, M., Golden Growth: Restoring the Lustre of the European economic model, World Bank, 2012 (overview) http://www-wds.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/2013/11/15/000442464_20131115123906/Rendered/PDF/681680PUB0v10G00Box379791B00PUBLIC0.pdf

 

 

 

 

 

Share

Pesquisar

Azulejos de Coimbra

paineliii.jpg